La teoría de principal-agente en los estudios sobre ciencia y tecnología
DOI:
https://doi.org/10.3989/arbor.2009.738n1054Palabras clave:
Teoría de principal-agente, teoría de agencia, ciencia, tecnología, sociología de la ciencia, economía de la ciencia, estudios de ciencia y tecnología, políticas públicas, políticas de ciencia, sistema de recompensas de la cienciaResumen
Este trabajo presenta la Teoría de Principal-Agente y la forma en que se ha establecido en los últimos años en los estudios de ciencia y tecnología. Para ello describe, primero, la propia teoría y la forma en que la han desarrollado la economía y la ciencia política. El trabajo revisa el modo en que estas disciplinas la han utilizado para explicar problemas relacionados con ciencia y tecnología o que los tocan lateralmente. Después se ocupa de las aplicaciones concretas en los llamados estudios de ciencia y tecnología. El artículo propone que la teoría se relaciona con las teorías clásicas de la disciplina, de las que a veces es sólo una formalización. Como propone, por fin, que las debilidades de la teoría se deben antes a su mal uso y a su escaso desarrollo que a sus posibilidades reales, a juzgar por su éxito en otras ciencias sociales.
Descargas
Citas
Abraham, M. y Prosch, B. (2000): “Longterm employment relationships by credible commitments: The Carl Zeiss Foundation”, Rationality and Society, 12(3), 283-306. doi:10.1177/104346300012003002
Aghion, P. y Tirole, J. (1994): “The Management of Innovation”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), pp. 1185-1209. doi:10.2307/2118360
Alchian, A. A. y Demsetz, H. (1972): “Production, information costs, and economic organization”, American Economic Review, 62(5), pp. 777-795.
Baert, P. (2001): La teoría social en el siglo XX, Madrid, Alianza.
Barnes, B. (1985): About Science, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.
Barnes, B. (1977): Interests and the Growth of Knowledge, Londres, Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Barnes, B. y Dolby, R. G. A. (1970): “The Scientific Ethos: a Deviant Viewpoint”, Archive of European Sociology, 11.
Ben-David, J. (1971): The scientist’s role in society, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice Hall.
Bendor, J. (1988): “Review Article: Formal Models of Bureaucracy”, British Journal of Political Science, 18(3), pp. 353-395. doi:10.1017/S0007123400005160
Bendor, J.; Taylor, S. y Van Gaalen, R. (1987): “Politicians, Bureaucrats, and Asymmetric Information”, American Journal of Political Science, 31(4), pp. 796-828. doi:10.2307/2111225
Bourdieu, P. (1975): “The Specificity of the Scientific Field and the Social Conditions of the Progress of Reason”, Social Science Information, 14(6), pp. 19-47. doi:10.1177/053901847501400602
Braun, D. (2003): “Lasting tensions in research policy-making - A delegation problem”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 399-321. doi:10.3152/147154303781780353
Braun, D. (1998): “The role of funding agencies in the cognitive development of science”, Research Policy, 27(8), pp. 807-821. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00092-4
Braun, D. (1993): “Who Governs Intermediary Agencies? Principal-Agent Relations in Research Policy-Making”, Journal of Public Policy, 13(2), pp. 135-162. doi:10.1017/S0143814X00000994
Braun, D. y Guston, D. H. (2003): “Principal- agent theory and research policy: an introduction”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 302-308. doi:10.3152/147154303781780290
Bush, V. (1945): Science, the Endless Frontier: A Report to the President on a program for postwar scientific re search, Washington, United States Government Print Office.
Caswill, C. (2003): “Principals, agents and contracts”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 337-346. doi:10.3152/147154303781780281
Caswill, C. (1998): “Social science policy: Challenges, interactions, principals and agents”, Science and Public Policy, 25(5), pp. 286-296.
Cole, J. y Cole, S. (1973): Social Stratification in Science, Chicago, Il, University of Chicago.
Coleman, J. S. (1990): Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University.
Crosby, E. U. (1905): “Fire Prevention”, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 26 (Insurance), pp. 224-238.
Dasgupta, P. y David, P. A. (1987): “Information Disclosure and the economics of Science and Technology”, en G. R. Feiwel (comp.), Arrow and the Ascent of Modern Economic Theory, Londres, Macmillan, pp. 519-542.
Dasgupta, P. y Maskin, E. (1987): “The Simple Economics of Research Portfolios”, Economic Journal, 97(387), pp. 581- 595. doi:10.2307/2232925
David, P. A. (2007): “The Historical Origins of ‘Open Science’ An Essay on Patronage, Reputation and Common Agency Contracting in the Scientific Revolution”, Documento de Trabajo 06-008, Stanford University Department of Economics.
David, P. A. (1998): “Common Agency Contracting and the Emergence of ‘Open Science’ Institutions”, The American Economic Review, 88(2) (Proceedings of the 110th Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association), pp. 15-21.
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989): “Agency Theory: An assessment and review”, Academy of Management Review, 14(1), pp. 57- 74. doi:10.2307/258191
Elster, J. (1986): “The Nature and Scope of Rational-Choice Explanation”, en E. Lepore y B. P. McLaughlin, Actions and Events, Londres, Basil Blackwell, pp. 60-72.
Epstein, R. A. (1985): “Agency costs, employment contracts, and labor unions”, en J. W. Pratt y R. J. Zeckhauser (comps.), Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Boston, Harvard Business School, pp. 127-149.
Ferejohn, J. A. (1999): “Accountability and Authority: Toward a Theory of Political Accountability”, en A. Przeworski, S. C. Stokes y B. Manin (comps.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, Cambridge, Cambridge University, pp. 131-153.
Ferejohn, J. A. (1986): “Incumbent Performance and electoral control”, Public Choice, 50, pp. 5-25. doi:10.1007/BF00124924
Fernández-Carro, R. (2007): “A principalagent model of public research with a retrospective payoff rule”, Science and Public Policy, 34(5), pp. 317-328. doi:10.3152/030234207X227152
Fernández-Carro, R. y Lapuente-Giné, V. (2006): “A Pied-Piper situation: Do bureaucratic researchers produce more science?”, Documento de Trabajo 8/2006, Departamento de Ciencia Política y Sociología, Universidad Carlos III de Madrid.
Fernández-Carro, R. (2002): Regímenes políticos y actividad científica: Las políticas de la ciencia en las dictaduras y las democracias, Madrid, Instituto Juan March.
Ferrater Mora, J. (1979): Diccionario de Filosofía, Madrid, Alianza.
Gibbons, M.; Limoges, C.; Nowotny, H.; Schwartzman, S.; Scott, P. y Trow, M. (1994): The new production of knowledge. The dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies, Londres, SAGE.
Gieryn, T. F. (1995): “Boundaries of science”, en S. Jasanoff et al. (comps.), Handbook of science and technology studies, Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage, 393-443.
Goldthorpe, J. H. (2000): On Sociology: Numbers, Narratives and the Integration of Research and Theory, Oxford, Oxford University.
Guston, D. H. (2003): “Principal-agent theory and the structure of science policy, revisited: ‘science in policy’ and the US Report on Carcinogens”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 347- 357. doi:10.3152/147154303781780335
Guston, D. H. (2001): “Boundary organizations in environmental policy and science: An introduction”, Science, Technology, & Human Values, 26(4), pp. 399-408. doi:10.1177/016224390102600401
Guston, D. H. (2000): Between Politics and Science: Assuring the Integrity and Productivity of Research, Cambridge, Cambridge University.
Guston, D. H. (1999): “Stabilizing the boundary between US politics and science: The rôle of the Office of Technology Transfer as a boundary organization”, Social Studies of Science, 29(1), pp. 87-111. doi:10.1177/030631299029001004 PMid:11623653
Guston, D. H. (1996): “Principal-Agent Theory and the Structure of Science Policy”, Science and Public Policy, 23(4), pp. 229-240.
Hagstrom, W. O. (1965): The Scientific Community, New York, Basic Books.
Hedström, P. y Swedberg, R. (1996): “Rational Choice, Empirical Research, and the Sociological Tradition”, European Sociological Review, 12(2) (Rational Choice Theory and Large-Scale Data Analysis), 127-46.
Kiewiet, D. R. y McCubbins, M. D. (1991): Capítulo dos, “Delegation and Agency Problems”, en The Logic of Delegation: Congressional Parties and the Appropriations Process, Chicago, University of Chicago.
Kiser, E. (1999): “Comparing Varieties of Agency Theory in Economics, Political Science, and Sociology: An Illustration from State Policy Implementation”, Sociological Theory, 17(2), pp. 146- 170. doi:10.1111/0735-2751.00073
Kiser, E. (1994): “Markets and Hierarchies in Early Modern Tax Systems: A Principal- Agent Analysis”, Politics & Society, 22(3), pp. 284-315. doi:10.1177/0032329294022003003
Kiser, E. y Kane, J. (2001): “Revolution and State Structure: The Bureaucratization of Tax Administration in Early Modern England and France”, American Journal of Sociology, 107(1), pp. 183-223. doi:10.1086/323656
Kiser, E. y Schneider, J. (1994): “Bureaucracy and Efficiency: An Analysis of Taxation in Early Modern Prussia”, American Sociological Review, 59(2), pp. 187-204. doi:10.2307/2096226
Latour, B. y Woolgar, S. (1986): Laboratory Life: The Construction of Scientific Facts, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University, Reimpresión, 1979.
Marí-Klose, P. (2000): Elección Racional, Madrid, Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas.
Mas-Colell, A.; Whinston, M. D. y Green, J. R. (1995): Microeconomic Theory, Oxford, Oxford University.
McCubbins, M. y Schwartz, T. (1984): “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms”, American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), pp. 165-179. doi:10.2307/2110792
Merton, R. K. (1968): “The Matthew Effect in science: The reward and communication systems of science are considered”, Science, 159(3810), pp. 56-63. doi:10.1126/science.159.3810.56 PMid:5634379
Merton, R. K. (1957): “Priorities in scientific discovery: A Chapter in the sociology of science”, American Sociological Review, 22(6), pp. 635-659. doi:10.2307/2089193
Milinski, M.; Semmann, D. y Krambeck, H.- J. (2002): “Reputation Helps Solve the ‘Tragedy of the Commons’”, Nature, 415(24), pp. 424-426. doi:10.1038/415424a PMid:11807552
Miller, G. J. (2005): “The political evolution of Principal-Agent models”, Annual Review of Political Science, 8, pp. 203-225. doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.8.082103.104840
Miller, G. J. (1992): Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Miller, G. J. y Moe, T. M. (1983): “Bureaucrats, Legislators, and the Size of Government”, The American Political Science Review, 77(2), pp. 297-322. doi:10.2307/1958917
Moe, T. M. (1984): “The New Economics of Organization”, American Journal of Political Science, 28(4), pp. 739- 775. doi:10.2307/2110997
Morris, N. (2003): “Academic researchers as ‘agents’ of science policy”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 359- 370. doi:10.3152/147154303781780326
Morris, N. (2000): “Science policy in action: Policy and the Researcher”, Minerva, 38(4), pp. 425-451. doi:10.1023/A:1004873100189
Morrow, J. D. (1994): Game Theory for Political Scientists, Princeton, NJ, Princeton University.
Mulkay, M. (1969): “Some Aspects of Cultural Growth in the Natural Sciences”, Social Research, 36, pp. 22-52.
Mulkay, M. (1991): Sociology of Science: A sociological pilgrimage, Bloomington, Open University.
Nowakovska, M. (1975): “Measurable aspects of the concept of scientific career”, en Determinants and Controls of Scientific Development, K. D. Knorr, H. Strasser y H. G. Zilian (comps.), Dordrech, D. Reidel Publishing Company, pp. 295-322.
Olsen, T. E. (1993): “Regulation of Multiagent Research and Development”, The RAND Journal of Economics, 24(4), pp. 529-541. doi:10.2307/2555743
Polanyi, M. (1969): Knowing and Being: Essays by Michael Polanyi, Marjorie G. (comp.), Londres, Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Polanyi, M. (1962): “The republic of science: Its political and economic theory”, Minerva, I, pp. 54-73. doi:10.1007/BF01101453
Pratt, J. W. y Zeckhauser, R. J. (comps.) (1985a): Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Boston, Harvard Business School.
Pratt, J. W. y Zeckhauser, R. J. (1985b): “Principals and agents: An overview”, en Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Boston, Harvard Business School, pp. 1-35.
Rip, A. (1994): “The Republic of Science in the 1990s”, Higher Education, 28(1), pp. 3-23. doi:10.1007/BF01383569
Shils, E. A. (1962a): “Politicians and scientists”, Encounter, 18 (enero), pp. 103- 107.
Shils, E. A. (1962b): “The autonomy of science”, en B. Barber y W. Hirsch (comps.), The Sociology of Science, Nueva York, NY, The Free Press of Glencoe, pp. 610-22.
Shove, E. (2003): “Principals, agents and research programmes”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5), pp. 371-381. doi:10.3152/147154303781780308
Simon, H. A. (1957): Models of man, social and rational: Mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting, Nueva York, John Wiley & Sons.
Smith, B. L. R. (1994): “The United States: The formation and breakdown of the postwar Government-Science compact”, en E. Solingen (comp.), Scientists and the State. Domestic Structures in the International Context, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan, pp. 33-61.
Spence, M. y Zeckhauser, R. (1971): “Insurance, information, and individual action”, The American Economic Review, 61(2), pp. 380-387.
Stephan, P. E. (1996): “The Economics of Science”, Journal of Economic Literature, 34(3), pp. 1199-1235.
Tirole, J. (1994): “The internal organization of government”, Oxford Economic Papers, 46, pp. 1-29.
Turner, S. (1990): “Forms of Patronage”, en S. E. Cozzens y T. F. Gieryn (comps.), Theories of Science in Society, Bloomington, IN, Indiana University.
Van der Meulen, B. (2003): “New roles and strategies of a research council: intermediation of the principal-agent relationship”, Science and Public Policy, 30(5): pp. 323-336. doi:10.3152/147154303781780344
Van der Meulen, B. (1998): “Science Policies as Principal-Agent Games. Institutionalization and Path Dependency in the Relation between Government and Science”, Research Policy, 27(4), pp. 397-414. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00049-3
Whitley, R. D. (2003): “Competition and pluralism in the public sciences: the impact of institutional frameworks on the organisation of academic science”, Research Policy, 32(6), pp. 1015- 1029. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00112-9
Whitley, R. D. (2000): The Intelectual and Social Organization of the Sciences, Reimpresión, 1984, Oxford, Oxford University.
Williamson, O. E. (1999): “Public and Private Bureaucracies: A Transaction Cost Economics Perspective”, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 15(1), pp. 306-347. doi:10.1093/jleo/15.1.306
Wolfson, M. A. (1985): “Empirical evidence of incentive problems and their mitigation in Oil and Gas Tax Shelter Programs”, en J. W. Pratt y R. J. Zeckhauser (comps.), Principals and Agents: The Structure of Business, Boston, Harvard Business School, pp. 101-126.
Wood, B. D. (1988): “Principals, Bureaucrats, and Responsiveness in Clean Air Enforcements”, The American Political Science Review, 82(1), pp. 213- 234. doi:10.2307/1958066 PMid:11616538
Wuffle, A. (1999): “Credo of a ‘Reasonable Choice’ Modeler”, Journal of Theoretical Politics, 11(2), 202-206. doi:10.1177/0951692899011002003
Descargas
Publicado
Cómo citar
Número
Sección
Licencia
Derechos de autor 2009 Consejo Superior de Investigaciones Científicas (CSIC)

Esta obra está bajo una licencia internacional Creative Commons Atribución 4.0.
© CSIC. Los originales publicados en las ediciones impresa y electrónica de esta Revista son propiedad del Consejo Superior de Investigaciones Científicas, siendo necesario citar la procedencia en cualquier reproducción parcial o total.
Salvo indicación contraria, todos los contenidos de la edición electrónica se distribuyen bajo una licencia de uso y distribución “Creative Commons Reconocimiento 4.0 Internacional ” (CC BY 4.0). Consulte la versión informativa y el texto legal de la licencia. Esta circunstancia ha de hacerse constar expresamente de esta forma cuando sea necesario.
No se autoriza el depósito en repositorios, páginas web personales o similares de cualquier otra versión distinta a la publicada por el editor.